Below comes a lecture
at the COST A7 economic conference in
Our lecture, however,
dealt mainly with the past:
The present version
is, however, not the edited book contribution. I did find an MS-DOS Word 4.0
text file from 1994, and various graph and data files
as MS-DOS Grapher, MS-DOS PaintBrush
or even simple data files. So the coming document is a reconstruction. Only
obvious mistypes have been corrected.
****************************************
ATTEMPTS
FOR CLOSING UP BY LONG RANGE REGULATORS IN THE
M. Banai1 & B. Lukács2
1 Multi-Ráció Cooperation, H-1117 Szerémi
u. 39.,
2 Central Research
Institute for Physics RMKI, H-1525
ABSTRACT
At the end of the
Migration Period the
1. INTRODUCTION
Prof. J. Kovács has
introduced in [1] the concept of long range regulators as the governors of the
social-economic processes of the different societies in different civilization periodes.
He identifies 5 long
range regulators in the modern age. These are:
1. Public sector, the
ratio of the public to private sectors.
2. The system of
education.
3. The system of
research and development.
4. Technical development,
innovation.
5. The system of
planning based on forecasting.
In the following paper
we try to formulate the close-up strategies in a region of
In summary our main
theses are as follow. In our approach we distinct two historical long range regulators.
These are:
I. The legal system of
the civilization.
II. The culture of the
civilization.
The five long range
regulators of modern age listed above had evolved from these historical long
range regulators. The long range regulator 1. follows from the historical long range
By the study of the
history of the different civilizations one can say that the two
In the second chapter
of this paper we show that in the last one and half thousand years one can
observe three distinct civilization existed up to the
II. World War in
the
civilization of west
the
civilization of east
the
civilization of east central
The closing up
attempts of east central
After
the II. World War east central
In the third chapter
of this paper we try to formulate the necessary quantitative conditions of this
closing up in the framework of a simplified growth model. According to the
results of this study for Hungary to catch up the per capita GDP of Portugal
(the less developed country of the EU) in 2005 it needs external financial
source between 8 to 16 billion USD distributed on the ten years time interval
increasing manner from a lower amount to a higher amount at the end of the
period. The lower external source (the bottom 8 billion USD) comes from the
criteria that the hidden economy can be successfully legalized, while the
higher external source (the top 16 billion USD) comes from the criteria that
the hidden economy cannot be successfully legalized.
2. THE REGION FROM
HISTORICAL VIEWPOINT
The topic of this
paper is the present and future of the close-up strategies of the
Some pieces of the Eastern Central European
history (e.g. some steppe connections) are rather exotic for Westerners. So the
Appendix gives brief notes of histories of important steppe nations.
Unfortunately the fine details of such histories are often in Hungarian, not
translated. The same holds for the history of the Basin.
First we define our
region, and then try to give the evidences for coherence afterwards. East
Central Europe here will be the self-governing or self-determining part of a
roughly vertical strip on the map, from the
For the western border
it is worthwhile to note three facts, two negative and a positive ones. First,
the region never belonged to the German Empire, therefore it did not share the
legal system of the Empire, furthermore, it never had
a complete and many-layered hierarchy of feudal vassallage.
The reason will be given immediately. Second, the substrate population here was
not the free German warrior-farmer (subjugated only later on the West) with his
own primordial piece of individual land. Third, in contrast to the Greek
Orthodox territories on the East, private ownership of lands and individual
rights of at least the ruling classes were fully established from the first millenium AD. These three initial conditions predetermined
a unique historical development for the region.
The lack of a
many-layered hierarchy of vassallage comes from the
war tactics of the Eastern mounted warriors, occupying East Central Europe
during the migration period. As excavations show, in the sixth century still
both German and Eastern societies had 3 different groups of the population. In
the
Originally the Avars, replacing the
During the subsequent
centuries, however, the social evolution diverged. To the west of a fault line
roughly along the Vistula and Danube the half-free
archers became insignificant (but remember Robin Hood, who led archers and
tradition is ambiguous if he were a poor nobleman or a commoner), and the most
efficient subclass of warriors became the heavy mounted knight, which type of
fighting needed enormous training and investment; around and below them the
light mounted and the foot warriors became dependent on them. The economic and
legal reflection of this evolution can be seen in the legal texts from the
empire of Charlemagne, where poor freemen are continuously offering the ownership
of their own lands to the wealthy for defence and for getting rid off the duty
of going into battle. So the natural result is the hierarchic society of more
and more partial rights of greater and greater number of population.
On the east of the
fault line, on the open steppe, the evolution went into the opposite direction.
The few heavy cavalrymen vanished, except that some such armament remained in
formal use in ducal families, and at the end of the Migration Period,
conveniently put to the occupation of Hungary by the Magyar tribes in 896 AD,
the Eastern armies were composed almost purely of light mounted archers. In
addition the steppe conquerors were at least partly nomadic, so they could
change the locations of their communities if needs be. Therefore land-ownership
was more or less temporary, while the property rights of cattle and horse were
well defined. As a natural consequence, when these migrating peoples stopped at
the west end of the Eurasian grassland and had to settle down, ownership was
got by the numerous and more or less equal light mounted archers. Their
relative number at the first millenium AD must have
been remarkable, since even at the end of the Middle Ages, after centuries of
economic inhomogenisation, the ratio of nobility is
around 10 % in Poland and Hungary, and definitely higher in Croatia.
So at the first millenium the full-right class of Eastern Central Europe is
numerous, and legally equal. (The first elaborate document of the Hungarian
constitutional evolution, the Bulla Aurea from 1222
AD, only 7 years after the Magna Charta, definitely states the unity and
equality of nobility; naturally an ideal whence reality deviated, which was
just the reason to demand a royal law.) Below them we find the subjugated
population in which the Germans were rare exceptions (as e.g. the Easternized Gepids in
This East Central
European territory gets Christianity from the West, from
In
As for
|
Fig. 1:
But the whole
administration, and specially tax-collecting of the
In 1054 happened the
Great Schism between
|
Fig. 2:
The first close-up
stage in
This convergence was
helped in some territories by Western immigration. This process was, however,
quite different in the three medieval sister countries. In
Otherwise a number of
Polish cities were founded by German burghers who remained the dominant element
for centuries there. But in Central and
In
In the same time some
families of the German nobility seeked fortune in
As for higher culture
and economy, also some definite convergence was seen, the Hungarian currency
followed Bavarian style from the first millenium, and
in the first half of the fourteenth century Hungary and Croatia (in an
English-Scottish style personal union between 1091 and 1918) immediately
followed the leading Italian states in the use of reliable golden coinage. As a
special explanation, note that in this time the economic, cultural and
innovative center of Europe was in Northern Italy,
just in the neighbourhood of Croatia and Hungary. The region was definitely not peripheric
in this time.
During this period
It is interesting to
observe the repeated recurrences of unifying tendencies within the region.
Between 1450 and 1500
a serious change happens in the position of the region. The center
of world commerce and innovations leaves
|
Fig. 3:
In the next two
centuries the
However
still the eastern and western boundaries of the region are intact. On
the east the border is still the
In the same time the
Ottoman occupation disturbs the internal commerce in
Still the continuous
fighting and the agricultural specialization have a consequence unique in
From the beginning of
the 18th century the
At the end of the 18th century the region looses territories on the
northeast. This is the 3rd partition of
The Napoleonic Wars do
not disturb too much this reduced region.
2.1.
The "reform age" of the
Emperor Francis I lost
the throne of the German Empire in 1806, when the western German territories
had been occupied by Napoleon. From that time the Hapspurg
rulers used the title of Emperor of Austria, although there was no state called
Now remember that
close-up strategies imply some
organisation and planning. If individuals learn techniques from more advanced
regions, such an activity may or may not be successful, may or may not result
in some close-up, but it is not a close-up strategy. We concentrate on
strategies. But the formulation and execution of a close-up strategy and
programme needs some kind of a body politic, which can make decisions and can
enforce them at least in some extent. By other words, some kind of a parliament
is a precondition. The optimal case would be an independent country, but in the
period just considered no part of Eastern Central Europe was independent in the
sense as used in the last century.
Indeed, the Hungarian
Parliament did formulate some steps for close up. Some laws created between
1825 and 1844 were parts of such a strategy. They wanted to change or
manufacture some long-range regulators of the national economy. We can classify
these ones into the following groups:
1)
Education, Research & Development, &c.
Introduction
of the majority language into legal life. Effects: extension of culture
to a large part of population; minority frustrations on the periphery.
Organisation
of a network of industrial training schools. Wanted effect: increase of
the level of industrial skills; however the law was not signed by the King.
Erection
of the
2)
Modernization of the legal system (of economy)
Creation
of separate Hungarian laws for finance (credit) &c.
Transformation
of the feudal ownership of lands into a Western-type property. Effect:
market of lands; ability for investment into agriculture.
Freedom
for erecting factories independently of the guild membership of owner or
employees. Effect: weakening of guilds.
3)
Infrastructure
Licences
and tax reductions for channel and railway creation.
Decision
for a permanent bridge on the
Planning and starting
of river regulation. Effect: prevention of regular floods on the Great
Hungarian Plains, therefore new agricultural land and safer traffic.
While these steps had
only a limited effect on close up,
2.2.
The age of dual monarchy
In 1867 the
Austro-Hungarian or Hapsburg or Danube Monarchy was rearranged according to an
agreement between the Austrian and Hungarian leading political groups, and in
1868 there happened a subsequent agreement between
In first approximation
the Monarchy consisted of two independent states, loosely called as
In
However in second
approximation there were some common matters between the two halves of the
Monarchy, namely defence and foreign policy. For these matters both Parliaments
sent delegations (with Croatian delegates as well in the Hungarian delegation)
to make decisions. In addition the two halves agreed in customs union for 10
years, which agreement was repeatedly renewed until the end of the First World
War.
Therefore
1) East Central Europe
as a whole was not a self-governing or self-regulating unit, because Galicia
and Dalmatia were ruled by Austria. However note that
the 1881 Linz Programme of the German parties of the
Austrian Imperial Parliament suggested the reorganisation of the double
monarchy by transferring Galicia and Dalmatia to the
eastern half. The suggestion was not accepted; however afterwards Galicia got
limited autonomy, while there was a continuous increase of influence of local
Croatians compared to local Italians in the administration of Dalmatia. In the same time Hungary continuously demanded
the transfer of Dalmatia to Croatia.
2) The core territory
of the region, the Carparthian Basin, i.e. Hungary
with Croatia, was in principle self-governing in all questions relevant in
economic development. The customs union was an agreement, and if great needs
be, free not to be renewed. However practically the existence
of this union established a coupling in economy.
3) On the
The situation will be
demonstrated on the Hungarian strategy of close up by long-range regulators.
The example has been chosen on the ground that until the First World War in the
region Hungary had the widest possibility to determine her own regulators.
Before this review two technical notes are
made:
1) The jurisdiction
process of Hungary results in laws named after the year and a Roman numeral
followed by a "tc" which indicates the sequentional order of the law in that year. For reference
we mention these numerals. For details see Refs. 2 and 9.
2) As told earlier,
the term "Hungary" needs a nontrivial definition. As a rule here for
cultural, and partly for legal, issues, Hungary stands for Hungary proper, not
including Croatia. On the other hand, for financial and foreign issues
"Hungary" is Hungary and Croatia.
While this needs some
attention, one cannot help, because this complication originated just from the
special position of the Central Eastern European lands, territories and
countries.
Regs. 1: Laws
As told earlier, the
legal system of Eastern Central Europe did not
originate from that of the Western Empire or any Western state. In addition,
the medieval legal system here survived until the middle of the 19th century, therefore modernization of economy
and society needed legal changes. (However, note the quantitative differences
between the Hungarian system and that of e.g. the Ancien
Regime in France. In Hungary i) no chain of vassalage
existed, so each noble was equal, directly depending on the Crown; ii) the
percentage of nobles was in the neighbourhood of 10 %; iii) some local groups
were more or less self-governing, and their territories free of the medieval
landlord system. As a result, the share in voting power for the Parliament was
higher in 1830 in Hungary than in contemporary modernised France.) The biggest
steps of this process followed each other as listed below:
1848. tcc (a whole
sequence): Establish legal equality of all male citizens, including
taxation according to common principles. (Note: this decision did not
completely eliminate prerogatives of nobility. E.g. all noblemen retained their
voting power, while commoners got it only above a certain level of income.
Reason: existing rights were not confiscated.)
1872. VIII tc:
Disbands the guild system. Henceforth economic activity is free for everybody.
1881. XLIV tc:
Supports the home industry. Freedom from taxation for 15
years if the factory is sufficiently up to date, either existing or under
construction. This law substitutes the custom laws for which the
Hungarian Parliament had no authority, such questions belonged to an
Austro-Hungarian body of delegations of equal number (and the Hungarian
delegation must have contained Croatian delegates of prescribed number too).
1890. XIII tc:
Widens the above preferences.
1907. III tc:
Gives the possibility for such support in any industrial establishment, if
economic reasons suggest.
At the beginning of
the new century complete legal equality of male citizens is an established fact
in Hungary; earlier preferred or dispreferred
classes, religions and other groups have been equalized, with some exceptions
in the voting power, and with special legal regulations for big lands of feudal
origin. This situation is comparable to the contemporary Great Britain, except
that the percentage of the population with voting power is lower, somehow
between 6 and 10 %. Industry and finance are completely free.
Regs. 2: Monetary, fiscal &c. regulations
1848: Customs agreement with Austria on the basis of greatest
preference.
1850: Austria unilaterally forces customs union.
1864: Stock market is established in Pest (one of the precursor
cities of the later capital Budapest).
1867. XVI tc:
Establishes customs union with
1867: Hungary accepts that she will not erect a central state bank.
1878: Reorganisation of the Austrian central state bank on
dualistic basis.
These regulations
generally were made as external agreements. As told above, neither Hungary, nor
Austria had the right to regulate her own external relations and defence: these
issues together with the finances supporting them were common issues of the two
independent states Hungary and Austria, determined by the mixed delegations of
the two Parliaments (or three, including the Croatian one), and in the lack of
any "federal" government the administration of these issues was done
by the offices of a common foreign ministry, a common ministry of defence, and
a common ministry for the finances of the foreign affairs and defence. (In
addition, the ministry of finances for common foreign affairs and defence
governed the Territory of Bosnia, whose position between Austria and Hungary
was rather obscure. Until 1908 the same ministry administrated the Novipazar Sandjak, belonging to
the Ottoman Sultanate, given by the Berlin Conference to Austria and Hungary
for administration, and separating Serbia and Montenegro. This task ceased by
the peaceful reoccupation of the Sandjak by the
Sultanate.) Neither part of the Austro-Hungarian complex had its own monetary
system, and had no right to introduce it. Separate customs territories were
possible in principle, but only after a long and difficult process of not
renewing the customs unions. Until the end of the First World War no separate
customs territories were established.
Regs. 3: Infrastructure
The whole Eastern
Central European region was behind the West in the middle of the 19th century
for the development of the so called infrastructure, including roads, railways,
enbankments, etc. The Hungarian government strategy
was to concentrate the available financial sources here, because an improved
infrastructure would result later in higher incomes, consequently taxes. Infrastructural
investments just after 1867 were high, while in this period their profit was
negligible. After a quarter century the share of this area went much down in
the investments, but the profit increased. The explanation is that the first
quarter century was necessary to reach the level of profitability in
development.
While these
investments were by no means purely made by the state, the state had a great
possibility to regulate them, and in this area the Hungarian (Croatia included)
souvereignity was complete.
The first process was
to promote investments into railway building. Up to 1875 this was achieved by
indirect means, namely the Hungarian Parliament guaranteed a fair profit for 10
years for anybody who got the licence to build a line. From 1876 the state
treasury started to buy up the private lines, by which the Hungarian State
Railways became the biggest employer of the country, and railwaymen became
state employees similar to soldiers, customs officers etc. This new status of
the Railways led to frictions between the Hungarian and Croatian authorities
about ruling the network. This indirect or direct investment activity
definitely helped the close-up in the density of railway lines.
The next step was the
building of artificial waterways and other regulations of natural waters; from
1878 the state started to organize the building of the so called Ferenc Channel between the two great rivers, the
1879. XXXV tc:
Regulates River Tisa. The total length of the menandering
river was reduced to 60 % by shortcuts. Result: floods became less
frequent, new lands became available for grain, and in the same time fishing
was reduced. A large part of the river became available for steam ships.
1888. XXVI tc:
Prescribes the regulation of
1895. XLVIII tc:
Orders the regulation of the
1897. XVI tc:
Nationalisation of the telephone system of
1898. IX tc:
Establishes the Hungarian Oriental Shipping Company.
Regs. 4: Education, Research & Development, &c.
1868. XXXVIII tc:
Orders education for everybody up to age of 15.
1872: Erecting the second university of Hungary in Clausenburg.
Later laws tried to
solve the problem of a centralised education system in a multilingual country.
2.3.
The
In 1900
Fig. 4 shows the
distribution of various religions in Hungary and Croatia in 1910, from an
East-West cultural viewpoint. No doubt, in that time religion strongly
influenced the everyday way of life. From the above viewpoint 3 blocks of
religions will be distinguished among the 7 religions individually handled in
the population counting process in the Basin.
1) Western. Includes Roman Catholic, Calvinist,
Lutheran, Unitarian and Israelite.
2) Eastern. The Greek Orthodox religion.
3) In between. The Greek Catholic Church, with Byzantian
rite but accepting the filioque dogma and Roman
leadership.
All other religions
counted as Others, remained in each county under 0.1 %
individually and 0.3 % together. (The Basin was divided into 72 counties, 63
Hungarian and 9 Croatian ones.) A block is considered "dominant" on
Fig. 4 if in a county it is the biggest. Then Fig. 4 shows that in 1910 in the
biggest part of Croatia+Hungary it was dominant to
belong to the West either directly (Block 1) or indirectly (Block 3). The
Eastern substrate was characteristic only in an Eastern wedge based on Serbia
and showing to the North. This wedge was partly a product of the 150 years of
Ottoman rule.
|
Fig. 4:
Religions in
Within the Western
group Roman Catholics were absolute majority, but mosaic-like one could find
counties of Lutheran and Calvinist majorities as well. No bigger unit with
Unitarian or Israelite majority existed; for both the highest ratio was between
20 and 25 %, in a Szekler county in Transylvania for
the first, and in Budapest for the second.
Hungary was a
multilingual country, and language is not a topic of this paper, not being
among the important long-range regulators. So we only note that in Hungary
proper (i.e. without Croatia) the biggest language group was the Hungarian
(Magyar) with 54.5 %. Croatia had some 65 % of Croats and 25 % Serbs. Religions
correlated with languages; in some cases strongly, in some cases weakly. In
Hungary Roman Catholics were mainly Magyars, Slovakians, Germans or Croatians.
Calvinists were almost exclusively Magyars, Lutherans mainly Slovakians and
Germans, Unitarians exclusively Magyars, Israelites mainly Magyars and in a
less extent Germans, Greek Catholics mainly Ruthenians
and Roumanians and Greek Orthodoxes
Roumanians and Serbs. In Croatia the correlation was
rather strong: Roman Catholics were Croatians, and Greek Orthodoxes
were Serbs.
Figs. 5 and 6 display
the employment structure in Eastern Central Europe in 1910, compared to that in
the rest of Europe. Eastern Central Europe is then characterised by a high
enough share of agriculture, however with non-negligible industry and commerce.
Note that within Eastern Central Europe the structure is "more
Western" or "modern" in the two countries not belonging to Austria,
so not governed from the West (of Central Europe). Since it is extremely
improbable that Austria would have "exploited" the poor countries of
Galicia and Dalmatia, we must see the result of a
close-up strategy, possible in the Basin due to the souvereignity
of the Parliament of the Basin (which we cannot name, because it had no name of
its own), but impossible with simple Landtäge. The
employment structure in the Basin was transitional between East and West, but
not unlike to the South. In Eastern Central Europe Hungary showed the
"most modernized" structure, similar to that of Italy. This
similarity would be preserved until c. 1965.
|
Fig. 5: Shares in employment
in
Table 1
Country |
Year |
Agriculture |
Industry |
Transport and commerce |
Other |
Eastern CE |
|
|
|
|
|
|
1910 |
69.6 |
17.0 |
4.0 |
9.4 |
|
1910 |
60.1 |
18.9 |
6.0 |
15.0 |
|
1910 |
79.9 |
6.2 |
6.1 |
7.8 |
|
1910 |
85.2 |
4.3 |
4.1 |
6.4 |
Western CE |
|
|
|
|
|
|
1910 |
42.3 |
25.0 |
13.5 |
19.2 |
|
1907 |
33.1 |
37.4 |
11.6 |
17.9 |
|
1910 |
38.1 |
34.5 |
10.7 |
16.7 |
|
Fig. 6: Employment structure
in other regions of
Table 2
Country |
Year |
Agriculture |
Industry |
Transport and commerce |
Other |
Southern |
|
|
|
|
|
|
1911 |
53.5 |
29.5 |
5 |
12 |
|
1910 |
51.0 |
23.0 |
6.4 |
19.6 |
Northern |
|
|
|
|
|
|
1911 |
36.4 |
27.3 |
10.0 |
26.3 |
|
1910 |
48.4 |
32.3 |
13.5 |
5.8 |
Western |
|
|
|
|
|
|
1910 |
24 |
48 |
12 |
16 |
|
1910 |
28.4 |
34.7 |
18.3 |
18.6 |
|
1906 |
42.5 |
25.0 |
14.0 |
18.5 |
|
1911 |
11.3 |
56.6 |
12.6 |
19.5 |
Eastern |
|
|
|
|
|
|
1905 |
82.0 |
7.3 |
3.8 |
6.9 |
Roumania |
1910 |
66 |
10 |
5 |
19 |
|
1897 |
77.2 |
11.5 |
5.7 |
5.6 |
2.4.
The post-war changes
In
1914 started the First World War. At its end, between 1918 and 1920,
serious changes happened in the region. Briefly they can be summarized as
follows:
1) The
Austro-Hungarian Monarchy was dissolved.
2) Hungary shrank to
the center of the Carpathian Basin. Her peripheries
went to states outside the region.
3) The personal union
of
4)
As a consequence one
may say that between the World Wars the region was represented by two national
economies, that of a new, smaller
The period between the
World Wars was a general stagnation for all of
We mention only 3
characteristic changes between the World Wars as follows:
1) The weight of
agricultural population continued to decrease: from 60.3 % (1910) to 50.8 % (in
1930); the weight of industry and commerce continued to grow. Roughly the
Hungarian employment structure evolved parallelly
with that of
2) In the industry the
employment share of small enterprise decreased from 47 % (1910) to 39 % (1938).
3) The use of
electricity fastly increased, so strongly that the
decrease of area did not result in a perceptible jump back, as can be seen on
the graph at the end of this paper.
All of these changes
are generally considered "modernisation".
2.5.
The socialist period
After the Second World
War soon
The period of planned
economy can be divided into two parts. Between 1948 and 1968 the economy was
directed by commands based on plans or superstitions. After 1968 regulations
became "indirect", so the long-range regulator concept became again
very useful, and from that time the country continuously reestablished
the Western connections, thus deviating more and more from her Northern,
Eastern and Southern neighbours. However, interestingly, the very important
turning point in 1968 cannot be seen in the aggregate economic data of Figs. 7
and 8.
|
Fig. 7: Net investment rate
in
|
Fig. 8:
Home consummed GDP/capita. Note: 1914=100
Fig. 7 shows the (net)
investment rate in the period. Before the Second World War this rate was
permanently between 8 and 10 %. The forced close-up is demonstrated by the
sudden jump to a higher value, and even more by the continuous increase of the
rate. Until the end of 70's the planned economy was able to maintain an
exponential growth of GDP (Fig. 8), however on the cost of forcing more and
more the investments. Even so, the exponential growth broke down at the
beginning of the 80's, and then the investment ratio started to return to a
moderate level similar to the inter-war times before planned economy. So the
close-up strategy of
At the end of this
Chapter we give Figs. 9-11, which compare the raw iron production, electric
consumption and GDP/capita for
1) In iron production
2) In electricity the
Hungarian and American developments were parallel between 1920 and 1980. No
close-up is seen, but no increase of lagging either.
3) In GDP/capita the
|
Fig. 9:
Crude Iron production in
|
Fig. 10:
Electricity consummed in
|
Fig. 11:
GDP/capita in
However, in the last
200 years the main desire in the Hungarian soul is not the close-up to distant
Now
the moral of Fig. 12. The long and systematic efforts of the Parliament
of the Basin resulted in the increase of the ratio from 0.58 to 0.70 until
1913. After the First World War the increase continued, ended with 0.86, so
catch-up was not impossible first after the Middle
Ages. The socialist era broke this trend, but in its first half returned only
to the ratio of 1913 (the last peaceful year of the Double Monarchy) and
stabilized there. However after 1973 the ratio drops steeply, and at the end of
the socialist era Hungary is back at a relative position similar to that at the
beginning of the Reform Age in 1825, 165 years before. In short 17 years she
slipped back as much as was the slow climb-up of 88 years before the
|
Fig. 12:
However mere 17 years
is nothing in the ages-old race of the two countries. What can be lost by
mishandling in relative position, can be won back as well in comparable time by appropriate
strategy.
3.
THE FORECAST OF THE PRESENT CLOSING UP ATTEMPT OF THE REGION BY MEANS OF A
GENERALIZED KOVÁCS -- VIRÁG DINAMIC ONE SECTOR ECONOMIC MODEL
In this chapter we
briefly present a quantitative approach of predicting the outcome of a possible
closing up strategy of the central European civilization to the west European
civilization. In this study we have determined the lower and upper bound of the
"cost" of the closing up growth path for
In [14] we formulated
a generalization of the Kovács - Virág
dynamic one sector economic model [15] and gave solutions optimalizing
the consumption function.
One can slightly
modify this model to obtain a quantitative predictions
about the time horizon of the present closing up attempts of our region.
The basic equations of
this modified one sector economic model are
dK/dt
= qsY - λK, (3.1)
Y = gK, (3.2)
where the savings rate s is a
function of the time
s = s(t),
λ is constant (depreciation
rate of capital stocks), the efficiency of the capital g is a function of the
savings rate and the time
g = g(s, t)
and the investment to capital multiplicator is a function of the time
q = q(t).
We have specified the form
of capital efficiency in [14] as follows
g(s) = βs(1 - s)γ, (3.3)
where γ is a constant in
time (around 4 in
In evaluating the
generalized Kovács - Virág
model we specified the time dependence of investment to capital multiplicator and the capital efficiency in the following
manner
q(t) = (q0Tq
+ q1t)/(Tq + t), (3.4)
β(t) = (β0Tβ
+ β1t)/(Tβ + t), (3.5)
We note that with the explicit time dependence in the saving rate, in
the capital efficiency and the introduction of the time dependent investment to
capital multiplicator enables the model to describe
transition processes a phenomenon characteristic of an economy being in closing
up state.
Numerical analyses
(not cited here) give the following values for the parameters in equations
(3.4-5). The Hungarian value of β0 was 3.53 y-1
at the end of 80's, while the contemporary Italian value was higher by some
2/3. The q value of the average of the 35 years up to 1986 was 0.84 in
β0 = 3.53, β1 = 5.76,
q0 = 0.84, q1 = 1.36;
what remains is the values of the characteristic times of changes in
(5.4-5).D We were looking
for a path of optimal total consumption in 15 years, which ends at the half of
the present Austrian GDP/capita.
The results are as
follows. The path cannot end at the target GDP/capita if either of Tq
and Tβ is larger than 3 years.
So, fast privatisation
and technological renewation are needed.
Loans without real
interest rate (e.g. a new
We have also
calculated growth paths of optimal total consumption in 10 years, which end at
the Portugalian GDP/capita in 2005 (assuming a 3 %
average growth rate for the
|
Fig. 13: A 10 years path optimalizing total consumption and enhancing GDP by 2.7 for
an economy with the average data of
References
[1] J. Kovács:
Regulative Planning. In: Economic Planning in Transition, eds. J. Kovács &. B. Dallago,
Dartmouth Publ. Co.,
[2] Berend
I. T. & Szuhay M.: A tőkés
gazdaság története Magyarországon 1848-1944. Kossuth,
[3] Ciepelewski J. & al: A világ gazdaságtörténete a XIX. és XX. században. Kossuth,
[4] Ocherki novoi
i noveyshci istorii SShA. Izdatel'stvo
Akademii Nauki,
[5] M. Banai, J. Kovács
& B. Lukács, in:
[6]
[7] Fl. Vopiscus Syracuseanus:
Divus Aurelianus, in Historia Augusta.
[8] Győrffy Gy.:
István király és műve. Gondolat,
[9] Hanák P. (ed.): Magyarország
története III-IV. Tankönyvkiadó,
[10] The data of the 1910
census were published in volumes for the whole Double Monarchy. Specially for the Hungarian data: Magyar Statisztikai
Közlemények, New Series, Vol. 42,
[11] Bogár
L.: Kitörési kísérleteink. Közgazdasági és Jogi Kiadó,
[12] Tarján
T.: Közg. Szemle 40, 815 (1993)
[13] Gy.
Molnár & T. Tarján:
Production Lag and Intellectual Background, in: Kovács
J. (ed.): Technological Lag and Intellectual Background,
[14] M. Banai
& B. Lukács: KFKI-1989-68
[15] Kovács
J. & Virág Ildikó: Közgazdasági Szemle, 28, 675-686 (1981)
APPENDIX
Keywords
of the History of Some Steppe Nations
Here some historical
data are collected for the convenience of Western readers about steppe nations
almost unknown in the West but mentioned in the present text and present in the
everyday historical memory of the
For brevity, if not
indicated otherwise, dates are meant in AD. A number of shorthand notations is
used, namely: E.=East(ern), S.=South(ern), W.=West(ern), N=North(ern), P.=Prince, K.=King, Kg.=Khagan,
R.=River, c.=about (in time), ct.=century, bw.=between.
"Basin" means
In some cases the
Hungarian literature is the most detailed (among the steppe nations
After the entry the
most common name used in the Basin in singular is given in brackets.
This Appendix has its
own reference list. When looking for an item in literature, note that in
Hungarian, Chinese and Japanese names family name comes first (at least when
the text is also in one of these languages).
Avars (Avar)
Possibly
the zhuan-zhuans of early Chinese chronicles [2].
C. 500. ruling in the Altai (now Kazakistan
and
The subsequent fate of
~ is obscure. Until 822 (or 840) names of Christian Avar
Khagans are known. (E.g. Theodorus and Abraham.) They were subjects of the
Frank Emperor so must have belonged to the Roman Church. ~ probably
were assimilated by the incoming Magyar tribes. Arguments exist for and against
linguistic similarity bw. tribes entering the Basin in 680 and 896 [6].
The exact time of the
settling of Serbs and Croats on the Balkan is a matter of argumentation. Some
scholars believe it to be pre-Avar, in which case ~ could
not have had a role in it. However it seems to have happened in the Avar era [5], [8] and the 6 Croat leaders of the migration
mentioned by Konstantinos Porphyrogenetos
have all Turk names [9] which, in any possible time, could not have been
anything else than Avar (or related). See also [10],
and for reconstructed previous locations, [11].
Bulgars (Bulgár)
Since
Bulgarian belongs to a special subgroup of Turkish languages (the r-group),
inheritors of Bulgarians can be recognised among Turkish peoples.
Chasars (Kazár)
Successor state of the
W. Turk Chaganate, core territory among the Volga,
Don and Mtn. Caucasus, Sarig
Sin (White Wall, in Russian times Tsaritsin, later
Stalingrad) keeping the narrow gateway between the rivers. The 7 Magyar tribes
lived on the W. periphery of the Chaganate bw. 750 and 830; in 830 the
Magyars picked up 3 rebel tribes of the ~ (the Kabars).
Mixed population in the Chaganate; the leading ~ Turkish.
Defeated but not subjugated by P. Sviatoslav of
Russia in 976, then decaying until the Mongolian invasion in ct. 13. Assimilated into the Golden Horde c. 1240. For some details
see [12].
As for culture, the Chaganate was a focal point of influences of Byzantine,
Arab, Steppe and Varaegian (Middle Swedish) cultures.
In c. 750 Begh Bulan
accepts the Old Testament religion in Karaitic form
(i.e. without Talmud), the common part of Judaism, Christianism
and Islam [13], [14], [15], [16]. The extent of conversion is obscure, but Karaitic communities survived in Krimea
and
The Kabar rebels of ~ entered the Basin with the Magyars in
896, transferring thither some Chasarian culture. Khasdai ben Yitzhak ibn Shaprut, Prime Minister of
the Cordoba Chaliphate contacted K. Joseph of the ~ c.
955. In the answer K. Joseph mentions Bulgarians and Magyars (or maybe Onogurs?) as previous Chasarian
tribes, having gone to the
Cumanians (Kun)
Kipchak
Turks fleeing from Mongols into the Basin in 1240, led by K. Kuthen. Now in
Gepids (Gepida)
East German tribe,
subjects of the Huns, leading the uprising against Huns in 454. Then rulers of the E. half of the Great (Hungarian) Plains, E. of
the R. Tisa. From c. 520
bitterest foes of the
Later fate is unknown.
Assimilated by Magyars, Slovaks, or, maybe, Saxons (Zips).
Huns (Hun)
Possibly
the Hiung-nus of early Chinese chronicles [2]; maybe
of mixed Turkish-Mongolian origin. At the end of ct. 3
BC triggering the erection of the Chinese Great Wall. BC 209-175: Kg.
Mao-Tun. Starting to W. in ct. 2 AD. Crossing the
Great King Attila
(433-453) rules an empire from
The later fate of the
~ is somewhat obscure. A state of the Black ~ is in existence in 681 when
Bishop
Hungarians (Hungarus, uhor)
Up to 1920 the common
word for subjects of the Basin (except
When applied to
language it always means the language of Magyars.
Originally the word
meant the Onogurs of the Basin in the ct. 8-9, and
went continuously to the new state and nation after 896 in W. use.
Jazones (Jász)
Iranian
horsemen, entering the Basin in ct. 14. Nearest relatives are the Osets along the Russian-Georgian border. In
Magyars (Magyar)
Dominant
population of the Basin from 896, and especially of the present
First
recontruable location S. of the Ural, c. 500 BC.
Possible connections with Huns moving to W. Later on the periphery of the W. Turkish and Chasarian
Khaganates until 830. Then moving to the W.,
and stopping to migrate up to now in the Basin c. 900.
Since Old Testament
religions were well known in the Chasarian Khaganate,
and the territory (especially the
Magyar tribes unified
the Basin third time (for first and second see Huns and Avars).
The language of ~ is
called Hungarian in the W. The present form of this language is mainly
Finno-Ugrian, i.e. a member of a family whose most W. language is Finnish, and
most E. ones are two Ugors (see later). However there
is a strong layer of Bulgarian (or r-) Turkish words. Nearest kins (without the Turkish words) are two small languages,
the Manysi or Vogul (6000
speakers) and the Hanti or Ostyak
(20000 speakers) just E. of the Ural, at the confluence of R. Ob and R. Irtis. Hungarian, Ostyak and Vogul constitute the Ugrish
subfamily of Finno-Ugrish family.
Onogurs (Nándor)
The W. term "
Petchenegs (Besenyő)
Sauromatians (Szarmata)
Iranian
horsemen, from ancient Hellene times, relatives to mythical Amazons.
(Distinction bw. Sauromatians and Sarmatians
ignored here.) At 500 BC in the
Jazyges
enter the Basin c. 20, and occupy the
Alans
divide into branches in ct. 2 BC with different fates [22]. E. Alans are dominated by Huns from 200, participate in Hun
movements and some go as W. as
Antae are in
This kingdom is
subjugated by Avars at the end of ct. 6. "After
AD 500 the Serboi, Choroates
and Antae (Alanic tribes) are gradually absorbed by
the Slavs over whom they reign." [22]. So the
Serbian and Croatian nations seem to have founded by Sauromatians.
Note that within the Indo-European family of languages the nearest kin of Slavian group is Iranian, to which Sauromatian
belonged. The possible successor states of Antae may be
In mediaeval Polish
historiography Sauromathians as organisers of the
Polish state was a commonplace.
A convenient steppe
timetable of migrations can be found in [26].
As for the possibilities
of Western influences in culture and legal system on peoples prior to entering
the
1) Huns moved too fast
to get any Roman influence. They lived together with Germans for decades, but
these tribes were Eastern Germans, at which no clear data for private property
of land &c. are known.
2) Avars
remained outside of East Roman or Christian territories until the
3) As for Magyars, various
pre-Basin Christian influence may have existed. Note
that Nestorian Christian missionary activity is proven in 781 as east as
REFERENCES
FOR THE APPENDIX
[1]
[2] J. Deguignes:
Histoire général des Huns etc.
[3] Ecsedi
Ildikó: Nomádok és kereskedők Kína határán. Akadémiai,
[4]
[5] N. Todorov
& L. Dinev:
[6] László
Gy.: In Évezredek hétköznapjai. Panoráma,
[7]
[8] C. C. Giurescu
(ed.): Chronological History of
[9] J. J. Mikkola:
Archiv f. Slav. Philologie 10, 158 (1927)
[10] A. Alföldi:
[11] Atlas zur Geschichte, Band 1. VEB
Hermann Haack, Gotha/Leipzig,
1981
[12] M. G. Magomedov: Obrazovanie
hazarskogo kaganata. Nauka,
[13] Kohn S.: Héber kútforrások
és adatok Magyarország történetéhez.
Athenaeum,
[14] A. Dubinski: private communication
[15] Galina Kobeckaite:
[16] A. Koestler: The Thirteenth Tribe -The Khazar Empire and Its Heritage. Random House, N. Y.
[17] L. Harkavy: Russ. Rev. 7, 79 (1875)
[18] E. A. Thompson: A History of Attila and the Huns.
[19] Németh Gy.:
Attila és hunjai. Magyar Szemle Társaság,
[20] M. Kalankatuaci: Patmutiwn
Aluanic asxarhi.
[21] L. Rásonyi: In Phil. Turc.
Fundamenta III,
[22] T. Sulimirsky: The Sarmatians.
Thames & Hudson,
[23] L. Schmidt: Geschichte der deutschen Stämme bis zum Ausgang der Wölkerwanderung.
Die Ostgermanen. 1934
[24] Győrffy Gy.:
István király és műve. Gondolat,
[25] Sz. Bérczi
& L. Szabó: In
[26] A. Toynbee: A Study of History. Weathervane, N. Y., 1979
****************************************
Endnotes from 2007:
A The present Croatian-Serbian
border is not too far from the Theodosius line; we suggested in 1995 that this
is not an accident. The fact is quite uninterpretable
in the paradigm of linguistic nations, fashionable in 19th century.
B The trend is not clear in 2007. It seems that the
fall-behind did not continue, but we are well below the 1913 relative level.
C It might seem
natural & symmetric to write
D The exposition in 1995 was rather laconic, so some
explanation would help. Parameter q expresses the “efficiency” of an investment turned into capital. In optimal case the investment
of the previous year would be a capital next year (amortisation being
explicitly handled in λ). We had performed numerical fits for some decades
using Hungarian and West German data (and a few other old Common Market
countries as well) and got q=0.84 for
E Paths discussed here have not been realized between 1995 & 2007: the growth rate was
always well below 10%. This is not the deficiency of the mathematical model.
The model is not a prediction, but
the optimal path (meaning maximal
consumption in an interval of length T with the given initial conditions at
t=0). The optimalisation means e.g. investment in the
best way. While the non-optimal growth would deserve discussions, an optimum is
of course never realised.